The Macro "Endgame": Growth, Gold, Deflation, and the Dollar (w/Lyn Alden and Eric Basmajian)

The Macro

Show Video

LYN ALDEN: So I'm Lyn Alden, and I'm here  with Eric Basmajian of EPB Macro Research.   And we're going to talk about a couple  different things related to his strategy   and about the global macro environment at the  current time. So, Eric, welcome to Real Vision.  ERIC BASMAJIAN: Thanks. Thanks for having me. LYN ALDEN: Yeah, so I'm looking forward to   this conversation because we've had a lot of  interactions in the past about some of the   things happening on the economy, and so I figured  it's great that we're able to talk about it. So   why don't we start by you giving the viewers  some idea of your background and what your   overall process is as part of your research? ERIC BASMAJIAN: Sure. So I'll start with a  

quick background for those that are unfamiliar.  I studied economics at NYU. While I was there,   basically my last year I worked at Morgan  Stanley full time on the wealth-management team.  I then jumped straight to the  buy side. I worked for a quant   fund in Midtown. It was good experience.  Learned some programming, some statistics. 

Economics was always my passion. So I was still  studying economics the whole time I was there,   basically reading everything that was available in  terms of academic research on debt and the impacts   there. I have a big focus on long-term trends. That's obviously where I ran into the work of   Lacy Hunt, who's been highly influential  to my thinking. I also studied quite   heavily Geoffrey Moore who used more of a  leading-indicator approach to the business cycle.   So using some of those statistical techniques  that I was working with at the fund, I was   creating some of my own composite indicators,  taking five or six or seven different data points   and combining them into one aggregate indicator. So basically what I do was I was taking  

the long-term trends, which you know sometimes  don't change for 20, 30, 40 years. And   it could be valuable for some people to just ride  that trend for a long time, but having experience   on the buy side with performance that gets marked  to market, it's just not realistic for most people   to stay on such a long-term trend like  that. So I tried to bridge that gap by   staying focused on those long-term trends but also  using a leading-indicator approach to pick up the   cyclicality within some of  those longer-term trends.  And I left the fund, started publishing my  own work, and that's kind of how EPB Macro   Research got started. This is going  to be the fifth year, and that's kind   of the 30,000-foot overview of what I do. My views now are that the long-term trends,   the impacts of debt and other structural forces  like demographics, are pulling us towards   weaker and weaker growth. But at the same time,  the leading indicators are pointing higher,  

which gives us some short-term momentum to the  upside. And that can make allocating a little   bit trickier than when the trends are aligned.  And I'm sure we'll have a chance to discuss   those two things, but that's sort of where  I shake out on the long term and short term.  LYN ALDEN: Yeah, perfect. I think that kind  of sets the stage to go in a couple different  

directions. I guess to start with, if we focus on  some of those leading indicators, can you give the   people a sense of what sort of indicators you  focus on, and what are they kind of telling you   about the next, say, six months or so?  Or what is the timeline you're looking at   when you say shorter term? ERIC BASMAJIAN: Sure. So for me,   short term is exactly what you said. So 6 to  12 months is sort of the range that I'm talking   about with the short term. Anything shorter  than that is a little bit too noisy for me.  So most of the leading indicators that I'm focused  on are very heavily centered in the manufacturing   sector. That's the most volatile sector, much  more than the services economy. And I believe   a lot of people overlook the manufacturing  sector, especially in the United States,   because they say it's such a small percentage  of the economy. It doesn't really matter. 

But the volatility of the manufacturing sector  is so much -- RAOUL PAL: Hi, I’m Raoul Pal.   Sorry to interrupt your video - I know it’s a  pain in the ass, but look, I want to tell you   something important because I can tell that  you really want to learn about what’s going   in financial markets and understand the global  economy in these complicated times. That’s what   we do at Real Vision. So this YouTube channel  is a small fraction of what we actually do.   You should really come over to realvision.com and  see the 20 or so videos a week that we produce  

of this kind of quality of content, the deep  analysis and understanding of the world around us.   So, if you click on the link below or go to  realvision.com, it costs you $1. I don’t think   you can afford to be without it. ERIC BASMAJIAN:  overlook the manufacturing sector, especially in   the United States, because they say it's such  a small percentage of the economy. It doesn't   really matter. than the services sector that it  actually still drives the ebbs and flows of GDP.   And my big process is following the rate of  change or the direction of growth in growth and   inflation. So those shorter-term manufacturing  sectors pick up different types of production  

backlogs or new orders to inventory, things  like that. And this situation with COVID sort of   caused a lot of these indicators to go haywire. And what I mean by that is when the lockdown   happened, we saw consumption stop for a  brief period of time. But then what we saw  

was consumption shift very dramatically towards  things that could be consumed at home, lots of   durable goods. And that caught basically every  supplier totally off guard, and what we saw was   inventories get depleted to basically the lowest  level we've ever seen as a percentage of GDP.  And then as a result, all of the suppliers  had to restock all of that inventory. And   we started to see a classic economic sequence  come through all the leading indicators where   commodity prices, specifically lesser traded  ones-- not really like copper or oil but some   of the industrial metals really start to pick up.  New order to inventory ratios started to explode.   And we sort of began this manufacturing  restocking rebound that's happening globally,   and it's causing a strong upturn in both the rate of growth and inflation,  which is a little confusing to people   because they look at maybe the labor  market that's still really impaired   or just the partial shutdowns in some parts,  and they say how is the economy improving? But   that manufacturing process can be so  strong, and that's what we're seeing now.

And it's still ongoing, and for the next  couple of months, I think that the bias for   both growth and inflation are still going to be  higher. And that's counter to my long-term view,   which makes the allocation process slightly  more difficult, avoiding or underweighting   things like long-term Treasuries that may  benefit from some of the long-term trends.   So those are kind of the indicators that  I look at, mostly manufacturing based. And   right now, they're still off to the upside. LYN ALDEN: Yeah, so if you focus on   those indicators and then how they pertain to  market prices, what sort of correlations or   causations have you found? So say you're accurate  about all these, the growth and the inflation.  

How do you translate that into an investment  portfolio, and how do you kind of monitor   risk or monitor if those trends are working out? ERIC BASMAJIAN: Sure. So I start with a balanced   framework, and this can be applied to any  sort of balanced framework. I gravitate   to the all-weather framework combination of  long-term bonds, intermediate-term bonds,   stocks, gold, and commodities, and that's  sort of where I approach every situation.   I come to the table with a balanced framework. Then I tilt in a direction that's most aligned  

with the long-term trend. So I'm always going  to have a bias towards the Treasury allocation   or the growth-slowing allocation, which tends to  favor Treasuries over things like commodities.   But then I also am cognizant of the short-term  trends. So when the short-term trends are pointing  

higher, you'd want to be doing the opposite,  basically. You'd want to be overweight or starting   to overweight commodities, risk assets, things  that perform well when growth is increasing,   and those are the correlations that I find. So when growth is increasing, specifically nominal   growth, equities perform basically the best out  of all those assets, commodities the second best.  

And within the equity sector, you want to be  tilted more towards the cyclical equities,   the small caps, the industrials, things  that benefit from that manufacturing upturn.  So I come to the table with a balanced framework.  I have a long-term bias to my long-term views.   Then I take the shorter-term indicators and  I sort of tilt or overlay that on top. And  

right now with the indicators pointing higher,  tilted more heavily towards commodities than I   normally would be, and my stock allocation  has small caps where it's typically   more large-cap defensive as a balanced framework. LYN ALDEN: And how are you seeing banks fitting   into that? Because I saw some interesting charts  the other day showing that banks and energy have   been key underperformers for a while now. So  a lot of people focus, for example, on growth   versus value, but value can be further separated  into defensive value versus cyclical value,   and it's really been in that cyclical value  where there's been a lot of underperformance.  And there's some kind of a recent rebound  there. We see them kind of up ticking,  

especially ever since we got some of the vaccine  announcements a few months ago. So how do you see   the energy and financial sectors kind of playing  out over the next six months or maybe longer term?  ERIC BASMAJIAN: So I'm a little bit more cautious  on the banks. I mean, I've had a long-term short   position in specifically the regional banks  since 2018, which has worked out quite well.   But I've pared that back to basically the smallest  allocation I could have on the short side because   these cyclical trends-- when there's an upturn,  the bias for long-term interest rates is higher.   So the bias for the yield curve is steeper.  That's going to tend to benefit the banks. 

But I'm cautious on the banks because they're  fighting such a secular trend of rock bottom   both short-term interest rates and  long-term interest rates that I'm aware   that the short-term trends can benefit them. But  I think that the banks, specifically the regional   banks-- I don't really deal too much with the  large banks that have much more diversified   revenue streams. Focusing mostly on the smaller  banks that are mostly just spread plays. And   I'm still cautious there, but I've  pared back the short position to as   small as I can because of the cyclical upturn. So once I see the indicators start to roll over   again and I would think that long-term interest  rates would start to have downward pressure,   I would increase that short position  again because I think the long-term trends   are very powerful against the banks. Looking  to things like Japan and Europe, I think that   our smaller banks will go the way of Japan and  Europe. Larger banks, totally different story.  Energy is interesting as well.  I don't like the energy sector.  

I prefer to just be exposed to the  commodities at this point. The energy sector,   high debt. The business model of the  energy sector, specifically the frackers,   is one that makes me cautious. Have  to spend a lot of capital to build a 

well that just depletes, and then you have  to spend more capital on another well. And   that business model, to me, is tough because it's  so reliant on constantly issuing new debt or new   equity that during these upturns, I prefer to  just be exposed to the actual commodity price   versus the energy sector. So I am still cautious on those too. I haven't   added those as long despite the upturn. I've added  just mainly small caps in general on a broad basis   instead of going down into the sector layer. LYN ALDEN: Yeah, I agree on the frackers. That's  

been an area I've been avoiding. For my energy  plays, I'm mainly focusing on the ones that have   kind of longer-life assets and the few out there  that actually have pretty strong balance sheets--   some of the international ones, for example. I guess speaking of international, so   we're both based in the US, and so  we have a somewhat US- centric view.   I know in my work I also carried out to focus  on other sort of countries because those can   give us kind of a different secular trends, which  could be helpful in a portfolio. So what extent do  

you incorporate international markets into your  framework, and do you have any allocations that   are kind of important for those at the moment? ERIC BASMAJIAN: Sure. So my work internationally   is much more broad. You've done some brilliant  work on individual countries. I focused mainly   on US and then ex-US, or if I was to break it down  a little smaller, mainly the developed markets. 

So the way that I play international, mainly  international equities, is you're right,   I'm very US- centric. When the dynamics that  I found, going back to the leading indicators,   is that when the leading indicators of US growth  are pointing higher, that generally means global   growth is going to be heading higher, and  especially because the manufacturing sector   is so correlated globally that when there's a  manufacturing upturn, there's a manufacturing   upturn basically everywhere. And during these upturns in growth,   as counterintuitive as it may sound, better  US growth tends to lead to a weaker US dollar.  

So when we have an upturn, the  dollar tends to get weaker. That   gives a big boost to everything international. So I have increased my international exposure   since basically I started to see the upturn in  the leading indicators around the summer of 2020.  

And that's when I started to increase the exposure  to international equities on a broad basis.   One of the allocations I have is  VXUS, so basically everything ex-US.   And that's basically the way that I play as far  as an allocation. The way I play international   is when there's an upturn, I expect the dollar  to lose value or the dollar to be softer, so I   allocate more heavily than I would on my baseline  approach to international equities more broadly. 

I don't often get into country specifics  as far as the allocation. I have research   broadly on the developed markets-- Japan, Europe  as a whole, the United Kingdom. Maybe we can talk   some long-term stuff about that. But as far  as the allocation, I'm mainly US or ex-US.   And when there's a growth upturn, I shift more of  my equity allocation to ex-US, which I have now.  LYN ALDEN: Yeah, it makes sense. And so I guess to  dive into those developed markets, when we focus  

on Japan versus Europe for the United States, do  you see any major differences between the three,   or do you see them all kind of on the same sector  trends? Like, for example, one thing I often   highlight is that one big difference between those  ex-US developed markets is that most of those have   more structural current-account surpluses. The  United States is on the opposite side of that.  Do you see that playing into your analysis at  all? Or basically if you were to kind of describe   the paths that those three are on, obviously  they have a lot of similarities, but   do you see them as kind all on virtually  identical path or somewhat divergent paths?  ERIC BASMAJIAN: Well, I don't think that  they're all on perfectly identical paths,   but my main framework is looking at the debt and  the impact that it has on growth there and then   the demographics. And those two factors, all the  countries are headed down basically the same path.   Like you pointed out, there's  different current-account situations.  But as far as the US-- and we can probably dive  into this. The situation with the US can be   interesting because in the short term, the larger  trade deficit can work to our advantage. And   part of my thesis is I do believe that the twin  deficit will get worse in the United States. 

And that can be to our benefit in the  short term because it can help us support   higher consumption and higher investment than  we otherwise would be able to have without   foreign support. It could lead to longer-term  problems down the road. We tend to see the twin   deficits get really bad with emerging-market  countries. It's a unique situation, I think,   with the United States. So it doesn't play into my  long-term thesis as much as I think it plays into   your long-term thesis, and this could be where  we slightly diverge on the long-term trends.  The way that I would view the United States  with the trade deficit is there's this view   that if foreigners immediately stopped funding our  deficits that interest rates would rise and the   currency would depreciate, and that's possible.  But the way that I would see it also is if the  

trade deficit started to shrink or  foreigners started to buy less of our debt,   that would have to come out of one  leg of our GDP equation as well,   and the leg that I believe would fall in  that scenario would be private investment.  So I believe that either way, a larger trade  deficit or a smaller trade deficit are still   going to lead to weaker growth. It's going to lead  to weaker real growth-- maybe not nominal growth,   but it's going to lead to weaker real growth in  either scenario because either we're going to be   hollowing out our manufacturing sector if we  have a larger trade deficit, or if we have a   smaller trade deficit and we're not able to get  external funding, we're going to collapse private   domestic investment, and both of those have  negative long-term consequences for real growth. 

And if our real growth continues to be  dragged lower, I think the inflation rate   ex some currency crisis will tend to follow  the direction of real growth as well.  LYN ALDEN: Yeah, so if you focus on overall  investment, do you have a way to separate kind   of what you think is going to be productive in  the long term versus what might be malinvestment   or what might be misallocated, or do you kind  of put all those together? Because obviously   it's hard to determine in advance. But basically I  think one argument we can make is that the United   States has had-- because as you point out, we're  very unique in that sense. As a developed market,   we have some of these characteristics that don't  quite fit other emerging markets because we are,   to a large extent, external funded  as the global reserve currency. And   so do you see that as kind of playing a role? I know that from my work, it's really kind of   showing up in some of these more extreme politics  or more a populist-versus-establishment situation   because we have a higher degree of wealth  concentration than most other developed countries.   To some extent, there's been a shift from a  developed-market labor to emerging-market labor,   but the United States has kind of accelerated that  more than some of the others because we've kind   of undermined our manufacturing base a bit more  by prioritizing other areas. And so, of course,  

we've had the benefit of technology  and health care and areas like that.  So I guess getting back to the question, do you  kind of-- when we focus on foreign investment,   do you have a way to kind of separate where  that's going or what that might be benefiting?  ERIC BASMAJIAN: The way that I look at investment  is I look at the velocity of money. and I look at   the money multiplier. And as long as those two  factors are continuing to move down, that would   argue that the investment's unproductive. So in my view, we can talk about velocity.   I think it's a little bit-- hammering on  velocity as a useless indicators I think   is getting to be an overused point.  I think there is value in the metric.  There's two main ways I think that velocity  increases. I think velocity will increase if there  

is an abundance of productive loans. People borrow  money, and it generates an income stream above the   interest that they're paying on the loan. Over the  long term, that'll raise the velocity of money.  The second thing that'll raise the velocity of  money is a complete loss of confidence in the   currency. That can cause the velocity to spike  very quickly. So it would be more coincident, but  

excluding loss of confidence in the US dollar,  which I don't think we're on the verge of in   the next year or two years or something like  that, unless we see the velocity of money start   to steadily increase, we can at least assume  that the debt is being used unproductively.  If the money multiplier is declining, that  means that the monetary base and the money   supply are going up at the same rate, which  means that most of the money supply is coming   from quantitative easing, which tends to  get recycled back into financial markets,   which I would view as unproductive because  we're borrowing money and putting it into--   we're not putting it into the real economy. So  it's not going to boost GDP is what I would say.  So I would say following those two factors,  money multiplier and the velocity of money are   the two best gauges we have to deem whether the  amount of new investment is productive or not. 

And given that those two metrics are still in a  pretty serious downturn, we can assume that the   debt that we've taken on, partly because of  the COVID situation and just malinvestment   in general, is still working against us. LYN ALDEN: So I guess if we focus on the debt   picture-- because that's something that we both  incorporate a lot into our work. I know Lacy Hunt   incorporates that a lot into his work as well.  And so if you focus on the long-term debt picture,   how does that tie into deflation and inflation?  Because we both know that high levels of debt can   be very deflationary, and it's kind of things  around the margin that I think is where a   lot of people debate. So if you were to take a  step back and explain why debt is deflationary  

and maybe how different types of debts could  interface differently with the economy.  ERIC BASMAJIAN: Sure. So I guess I'll give  you my summary of all of the research on debt   that I find useful. There's remarkable  consistencies across some of the research on debt,  

and I note four or five consistencies. First is  that a little bit of debt is good. A little bit of   debt can boost growth and can be pro inflationary  because it can raise output above potential for   a period of time. So that's the first thing. The second thing is that a lot of debt is bad   for growth. The third thing that's remarkably  consistent is the thresholds that are outlined   in these various academic papers at which debt  starts to really have a negative impact on growth.  

And this is not just Reinhart and Rogoff. There's  dozens and dozens of studies that have been   replicated across different statistical techniques  that all seem to settle on the range of about   80% to 90% of GDP, and that's not just at the  government level. That's 80% to 90% of GDP across   the household sector, the business sector, the  government sector, the financial sector. Any   one of those sectors tends to cross 80% to 90% of  GDP, we tend to see a negative impact on growth.  The other thing that's consistent, the last  thing, is that once you surpass those thresholds,   the decline in growth gets nonlinear. So  it starts to look like a U. A little bit of  

growth helps. Then it starts to level off,  and then it becomes like an upside-down U.   So those are the four consistencies. And if we map the US long-term growth-- I   published some of these charts on Twitter. Look at  like a 20-year annualized growth rate of real GDP.   Our growth rate's taking on that upside-down  U shape, very consistent with the research. 

So then you say, why is the  debt causing that downdraft   in growth and the inflation rate's following? Mainly it's because private investment  is what tends to suffer as debt levels   get too high. And when private investment suffers,   the infrastructure of the society  tends to collapse. You tend to have   overcapacity in certain issues or unutilised  resources, things like too much excess labor.  

And when you have too much capacity in some areas,  then that tends to bring the inflation rate down.  So the lack of investment tends to suppress the  real growth rate, and then the real growth rate   tends to drag the inflation rate down because as  growth gets lower, you end up having an abundance   of resources that you're not using for that  growth, and that tends to drag the inflation   rate lower. So that's kind of how I square the  debt picture with the growth and inflation picture   is that too much debt ends up reducing private  investment, which ends up reducing real growth,   which ends up causing an excess of  capacity in certain areas of the economy.  LYN ALDEN: And if we focus on correlation  and causation, is there a way to separate,   in your view, which variable is more causal  than the other? Because if you focus on, say,   a failing business, if their growth is going  down, one of the things they tend to do is take   on more debt to try to make ends meet until they  run into a problem. And so given that multiple   economies do have a demographics issue where  they're becoming more top heavy in terms of age,   the ratio of people, say, receiving benefits  versus paying into benefits makes things very   challenging. And, of course, that, over time,  translates into slower and slower GDP growth. 

There's also a certain amount of saturation. If  you go from emerging market to developed market   and you start to meet a lot of the needs  of the people, growth ends up kind of   being somewhat asymptotic in that sense. So  do you view that the debt is surely causal   of that slower growth, or is that slowing  growth then lead policymakers or businesses   to begin kind of taking out more and more debt? ERIC BASMAJIAN: That's a good point. I think that  

if the debt is productive in the sense that it  generates an income stream above the interest,   then I believe that it doesn't necessarily have  to slow growth, and I think that we would be able   to see that in the velocity of money. The second thing is we can stack up   how [AUDIO OUT] we're generating per dollar  of debt and see that every dollar of debt   now is generating less and less growth. So I  think that that's a valid point that you make.   I think that there's no-- I don't think that  we can say that all debt's bad and that every   use of debt is going to slow growth. I think  that it's the use of debt in the various ways. 

I think there's a lot of available research  that suggests that-- I'm not making a political   point-- that transfer payments tend to be a  very low-productive use of debt, and one of   the things that we've generated the most amount  of debt through is through transfer payments.   So I think that transfer payments are causal  in terms of the slowing of growth because   it tends to reduce private investment. And the point that I would always circle   back is that if we measure real GDP per  capita, that's effectively the standard   of living. It standardizes for population,  standardizes for inflation. It's basically   the productive capacity of the economy. So the litmus test I would say is, if the debt is   being used to raise the productive capacity of the  economy, then all is fine. But, if the debt's not   being used specifically to raise the productive  capacity of the economy, then all is not fine. 

And when we use a lot of transfer payments and  when we just look at the GDP equation itself,   higher levels of government spending will result  in lower investment just on an accounting basis.   So I think that as long as the debt is being  used productively-- I know World War II is   an example that you've done a lot of work on.  That may be different than today because of how   different the debt was used. So I think it  can be both causal and-- in certain senses,   depending on the way that it's used. LYN ALDEN: Yeah, one thing is if you focus on  

the 1940s World War II period, the industrial base  roughly tripled. It went up something like 2 and   1/2 times over the course of that decade. And then  even after the war it had somewhat of a pullback,   but it didn't pull back anywhere near to where  it was because of course they were able to   repurpose that for a lot of domestic uses. And so a lot of people focus on the war   took us out of the depression or  whatever, but it was really-- I mean,   all the things we did overseas was mostly  destructive. It was more about kind of rebuilding   the industrial base and things like that. And so how would you describe that as kind  

of conflicting with kind of the MMT approach?  Which is basically the argument that if you,   say, increase money supply a lot,  if you increase deficits a lot   but it comes along with increased productivity,  that should keep inflation low, and that therefore   they can get away with more of that kind  of deficit spending or monetary increase.   Whereas you're saying somewhat of the opposite,  that if the industrial base stays low, that  actually has a deflationary  impact. So how would you kind of   clash those two views, do you think, as it relates  to whether or not higher productivity can tame   inflation or if it can lead to deflation? ERIC BASMAJIAN: Sure. So I would say that  

with the MMT, where it goes wrong is that there's  no mandate to increase the productive capacity of   the economy. Most of the MMT is that we can do job  guarantees. And if we say, OK, the government's   going to run a huge deficit and it's going to  pay people to dig a hole and fill it back up,   sure. They can run a big deficit and do that  and they can pay those people, but if it's   not increasing the productive capacity of the  economy, it's not increasing standard of living   at all. Then the economy can't really advance.  So I don't see how that would be inflationary.  The second thing is that when the government  spends money, it steals resources from the   private sector-- not in a balance-sheet sense.  We could always lever up and invest more money,   but it steals resources from the private sector.  It steals that labor. It steals those raw   materials from the private sector that may be  able to use those resources more productively. 

So if we keep sending people money and sending  people money with larger deficits, all we're going   to do is divert resources towards consumption  and government spending. And then again in the   GDP equation, GDP is equal to consumption plus  investment plus government spending. If G goes   up and C goes up, then I has to come down. And if  I comes down and we have less jobs available here   and productive jobs here, then we have an  abundance of labor. And if we have an abundance   of labor, that drags down wages. And to me, that's  the deflationary impact that MMT doesn't call for.  And the money supply would certainly go up quite  rapidly. But in that scenario, the velocity of  

money wouldn't increase because it doesn't  fulfill the criteria of an income-generating   use. So that, to me, is a deflationary impact. LYN ALDEN: So one thing I like to do is kind of   use extreme examples to sometimes find kind of the  boundary of where a point can go, and then we can   kind of bring it back to a moderate example. So  if you look at, say, one of the states that's had,   say, a major inflation like, say, Venezuela  for example-- a combination of bad governance,   bad productivity, massive increase in the  money supply. And so we had a situation  

where the money supply goes up dramatically,  but their overall productive capacity has   either flat lined or gone down, and basically  the whole incentive structure is messed up.   Then you get a pretty high inflation rate. So, hypothetically, if you were to say everybody   has double as much money as they have now-- let's  bring it back to United States. Everyone has   twice as much money as they have, but  we still have the same amount of homes   out there. The same amount of cars are made. The  same amount of copper and energy exist, the same  

amount of all these kind of different goods and  services. How would that translate into prices   of those various goods and services and assets? ERIC BASMAJIAN: Sure. So I would just like to   create some parameters here. Let's assume  that the government sent everybody a check   of a million dollars. I guess  that's sort of what you're 

saying here. There's no doubt that  that would raise nominal GDP growth.   Absolutely. In the short term, everyone gets  a check. It would raise nominal GDP growth.  The question is what happens in year two? Does  everyone get another $100,000 check? If they do,   they're going to need more than that to keep  nominal GDP growth on an upward trajectory because   they're going to need the same amount of money  plus they're going to need additional if they want   to have growth. So if we're talking about these  one-time payments, it can cause a short- term   increase in nominal GDP. That's partly what we're  seeing now. But as soon as those payments stop,  

GDP goes on a downward trajectory again. So if we're talking about one-time payments,   then you're going to have a short-term boost in  growth and a short-term boost in inflation until   people have a-- because the rate of change in  their income would go down. They have, let's say,   20% income growth, and then there would be 20%  income decline. So once the prices rose in year   two, they would have less income against higher  prices, and that would drag the prices back down.  If you sustained it and you did $100,000 this  year, $105,000 next year, $120,000 in year three,   that can keep the upward trajectory on prices.  But again, it's only as good as the last payment.   As soon as the payments stopped, income growth  would go right back down, and then you'd have   less income against higher prices. And I believe  that that would, in turn, bring the growth rate  

and the inflation rate back down. LYN ALDEN: Unless, of course,   we got to the part where there would be  crisis of currency or something like that.  ERIC BASMAJIAN: Exactly. Of course. LYN ALDEN: And so one thing I know we've seen this   past year is that some people, when they receive  the stimulus checks, they pay down some degree of   debt. So we saw some credit-card debt go down.  I think it was something like $100 billion last  

I checked, which sounds like a lot of money but  it's actually a reasonably small percentage of   the amount of debt out there. So if you were to have those massive   payments. Let's say we have very large, say,  fiscal deficits over the next several years, and   people end up deleveraging some of their private  debt. Does that have a somewhat inflationary bent,   or would that remains deflationary in your model? ERIC BASMAJIAN: Well, I think it depends because   if we go back to World War II, let's say, one  of the differences then was that wages as a   percentage of income reached almost 70%. So most  of people's income was through wages, and we saw   the savings rate rise pretty dramatically during  that time. So people were saving out of income.  Now we see the savings rate rise. There was a  brief spike, but it's savings out of government  

dissavings. It's not savings out of income. We see  wages as a percentage of total income is actually   less than half now. It's fallen to 49%. So all we're doing is we're not really   deleveraging the total debt pie. We're just  shifting debt. We're basically passing the  

baton from the household sector to the  government sector. So it would cause the   household sector to fall a little bit, and then  it would cause the government sector to go up.  What that would do, in my way of doing things, is  it would make additional debt from the government   sector even less productive because you'd have  more of a nonlinear benefit at the government   level. And then it would make the household debt,  new household debt, more productive, but then we'd   be delevering just to relever. So I don't see a  way that that boosts the long-run rate of growth   or the long-run rate of inflation so long as we're  just shifting debt from one sector of the economy   to the other because if we're increasing debt  on the government level, we're still going to   be increasing government outlays as a percentage  of GDP, which means some other part of GDP has   to be going down as a percentage of the pie. And typically government debt is geared towards  

facilitating consumption. Well, what we're  continuing to see is rising G and rising C,   and that's going to put downward pressure on  I. Or, to your thesis, if we want to sustain   investment, we're just going to have to explode  the trade deficit. So either way, I think if we   just shift the debt to the government, the result  would be lower I or higher trade deficit to   produce everything that we're trying to consume. LYN ALDEN: And maybe here we could focus on, say,   the mechanics of kind of allocation  decisions. So say you are a private   capital allocator. You're a venture fund or  any sort of pool of money that's looking to  

invest in businesses. Maybe it could be a bank  making loans, or maybe it could be more of a fund.  So to what extent does the government, say, doing  transfer payments or issuing their own debt,   how would that influence the decision  of those allocators on which projects   that they want to allocate capital to? So how  does that end up reducing their allocations?  ERIC BASMAJIAN: If you were a venture fund  trying to-- well, I don't know if it would   impact their decision all that much because what  the research shows, the research that I've read,   is that income decisions are mainly based on  long-run trajectory of income, not necessarily   one-time payments. So I think that perhaps you'd  allocate more towards goods consumption or goods   producers, but we don't really produce a lot  of goods here, so there's not really a whole   lot of investment decisions to make. And this sort of plays into the whole   malinvestment thesis is where do they invest?  There's nothing to invest in over here. If you   want to invest in people that produce  the things that we're going to consume,   it brings investment to overseas. So I don't know if that changes the  

equation all that much for me in terms of where  I would invest if the government is going to   be doing a lot of transfer payments. What we  see is when the government is doing a lot of   transfer payments, it's having a downward  impact on labor. People are working less,   and what we're seeing is more consumption  of technology at home and goods at home.  So I guess if you were to allocate, it would be  towards technology producers and goods producers.   But the goods producers are offshore, so I  think that the allocation would, I guess,   be bent towards consumer-based technologies and  fintech. And I guess things like that would be   the primary allocator. But  

I think that the one-time payments are different  than a sustained income trajectory because I don't   think people are going to make investments  based on a one-time spike in consumption.   Otherwise we'll be stuck with overcapacity once  that consumption dies down. It would have to be   based on a long-run trajectory of income growth. LYN ALDEN: Makes sense. And so for a lot of this,  

we focus more on the manufacturing side. So I  guess if we-- do you do a lot of work on the   real-estate sector at all? Because I know that's  another significant contributor to the economy.   It can impact commodities. It obviously impacts  people's household spending habits to some extent.  So what are you finding in  the real-estate markets?   And do you have any kind of shorter-term or  longer-term view on where those might be headed?  ERIC BASMAJIAN: Sure. So one thing I find  interesting with the real-estate market   now is we've seen a pretty steady  rise in long-term interest rates,   yet partly because the Fed is buying so  many mortgage-backed securities, mortgage   rates actually continue to make new lows despite  higher long-term interest rates. So that's putting  

a lot of upward pressure on housing prices. And I think what we're seeing now in the   real-estate market is a huge demographic shift,  obviously, out of cities and to suburbs. That's   having, as you mentioned, a huge reflationary  benefit that's playing into this manufacturing   upturn because everyone has to refurnish  a new home, and there's a high-velocity   impact to that for a brief period of time. My view is that that's going to continue.   I think that there's still legs behind that.  I think the indicators of the housing market   are still pointing higher. There's a lot of  new residential construction still going on.  But since we're basically just stealing  real estate from the cities to the suburbs,   I think that there will be a hangover effect  once that whole demographic shift is complete.  

So I think that once everyone buys a house  and that pent-up demand kind of is exhausted,   we're going to have a hangover of all of  those refurnished goods that are obviously   all backordered now. You can't get a dishwasher,  as your friend Luke Gromen was trying to get.  So I think that we're going to  have a hangover effect there.   But as long as the Fed keeps stepping on the  mortgage-backed securities and keeps interest   rates so low, it is going to facilitate  more of a shift from renters to buyers.   But that's going to be a problem if those  mortgage rates ever start to go up because   there's going to be several million  new home buyers that find themselves   immediately underwater because the price is  so sensitive to changes in mortgage rates. 

So I think that right now it's powering this-- or  it's an added layer to this manufacturing upturn,   and that's still going to continue. But  once that demand is sort of saturated,   then we're going to have a hangover effect because  the increase in the real-estate market wasn't from   newfound income or newfound jobs. It  was mainly just a demographic shift.  LYN ALDEN: Yeah, and at those lower  interest rates. ERIC BASMAJIAN: And the   lower interest rates. LYN ALDEN: That's one of the things   I've been watching too because when you're kind of  determining the valuation for a company, whether   it's a value stock or a growth stock, obviously a  big impact is what discount rate you're going to   use and what target rate of return you're seeking. And back, for example, in the dot com bubble,   Treasuries were yielding over 6% for a big  chunk of that. And I like to refer to these  

cyclically adjusted earnings yields, which is  the inverse CAPE ratio, because that kind of--  ERIC BASMAJIAN: That's my favorite as well. LYN ALDEN: --yeah, smooths out. And so that   was the lowest that stocks ever were  compared to, say, the 10-year Treasury,   and so that was a clear bubble. I think what makes things challenging here   is that the interest rates are so extraordinarily  low that of course people have a tough time   determining what you pay for, say, a software  company that might be growing at 10%, 15%, 20%   a year. You're not sure how long that's going  to go, but you're willing to pay a pretty high   multiple for it because interest rates are so  low. So I guess in your model, you see kind of a  

secular stagnation yield. So you think that  after whatever kind of bump we're having now,   we're going to return to lower and lower yields.  So your view would probably infer that some of   those really high growth stock valuations probably  remain elevated for the foreseeable future,   or would you see it differently than that? ERIC BASMAJIAN: No, I do see it that way. And   I think that the-- I do view equity valuations  in a very similar way. I use the CAPE ratio,  

and you square it up against interest rates. I tend to caution when I square it up against   interest rates because interest rates have an  embedded growth assumption in them as well.   So if interest rates are zero, that can raise  the discount rate, but that also is implying   that there's really bad economic prospects  out there as well. So what we see is that it   raises the valuation for certain companies. It  doesn't raise the valuation for other companies.  So like in Europe, let's say, anything  that's a financial has a multiple of 6 or 7   even though interest rates are negative. So if the  company has no growth and it's a melting ice cube,   then the lower interest rate does not  warrant a higher multiple. But to your point,  

if you have a company that's growing 20% or 30%  legitimately and you discount that at 0% or 1%,   then the valuation can get kind of crazy. Now, where this gets into kind of a wonky   regime is Amazon is one thing. They have  legitimate revenue growth that's double digits.   Fine. The question here is now people are  selling a story that we're going to have growth   in the future, and there's nothing really  there. It's just the prospect of growth, and   investors are still bidding up those companies. And that's where we sort of I think get into  

some dangerous territory where you can make  the argument that if the company delivers   on said growth, then the valuation should be  XYZ. But we have to see the companies deliver   on said growth, which may be different  than Facebook, Amazon, Google. These are   established companies, huge cash flows,  legitimate cash flows, double-digit growth.   Hard to say that they don't warrant the  higher valuation with the lower discount rate. 

If you're in a sector like financials that  your growth is just structurally impaired,   we're not seeing those companies get reflected in  higher multiples at all. And then the question is   a company that's just selling a story of growth,  what do you do with that? I tend to just avoid   those companies altogether because I don't know  exactly what the rational way to value those   companies are and the way to discount how likely  they are to deliver on those growth assumptions.  Tesla would be the prime example of that. I  think they actually have declining revenue growth   last time I checked, but the multiple doesn't  matter because it's a story stock, and it's the   growth of we're going to have a million taxis. The  growth is going to be so explosive in the future   that we warrant this huge valuation today  based on the current rates. And that's a  

little bit out of my game because I don't know  what the chances of them delivering on that are.  LYN ALDEN: Yeah, that's the bellwether I'm  watching too because if you look at, say,   the amount of cars they delivered over, say,  the 12 months, it's something like a 35%   increase over the previous 12 months, which is  reasonably impressive given the pandemic. But then   their stock price went up something like 900%. ERIC BASMAJIAN: That's right. 

LYN ALDEN: So it's like it clearly warranted some  sort of increase, most likely. But then it's to   what degree of increase did it warrant? ERIC BASMAJIAN: Exactly.  LYN ALDEN: Especially because  they're not, say, a software as a   service company. They're a hardware-focused  company. They actually have expenditures.   And so they're borderline break even depending  on exactly how you want to measure profitability.  I guess one way we could take this discussion is  to kind of focus on the end game here. So I think   that's people that have the more inflationary  outlook or people have more of a deflationary   outlook, that kind of converges towards what  is the end-game scenario for this? Because   the deflationary outlook is one of those things  where it keeps going in a certain direction until  something breaks. Either the currency  breaks or civil unrest rises because  

people have-- their lifestyle decreases. So I guess you could take whatever direction   you prefer, but I guess focusing on the  economic aspect or some of the tail-risk   outcomes that could change some of this,  how do you see this kind of long-term   grind towards deflation unfolding after it  hits kind of maybe certain breaking point?   Especially because I think you point out that  the deflation is actually accelerating. It's   not just a linear decline. It's kind of an  exponential. So how would you kind of see that  

resolving long term? ERIC BASMAJIAN: Sure. So I think   that's the critical point. I think that the-- and  it's really the real GDP per capita which is the   critical measure, and that's going to continue  to decline. And we're seeing a lot of the, quote,   unquote, end game play out as we see with all  of the civil unrest. That's all totally related.  And one of the points that I would make is that  we've seen real GDP per capita from, let's say,   like the '50s to the '80s was growing in the  high 2s to low 3s on a really sustained basis.   We've seen that drop to about 1.2%, 1.3%  on a long-term basis, but that's just an  

average of real GDP growth. As you mentioned,  our wealth concentration is pretty extreme.  So even though real GDP per capita is 1% on  average, there could be-- and I don't have   the exact numbers, but there could be 40%, 50%,  60% of the population that's already experiencing   a decline in their standard of living. So that  civil unrest is manifesting itself in a lot of   different ways, including a higher demand for  transfer payments, which in my model is going   to exacerbate the situation in terms of real  GDP. I think it's going to make that worse.  Where the end game gets kind of interesting for me  is that a lot of the inflation camp-- and perhaps   you can comment on this because I'm curious-- is  that we can solve some of this through inflation.   Where I tend to get a little tripped up with  that is if the target that we're looking at   is increasing people's standard of living  to quell some of the social unrest, we need   to do something to raise real GDP per capita.  Debasing the currency or inflation doesn't seem  

like it's going to achieve that goal, which may  not result in any less unrest than we're seeing.  The second thing is I don't think we have  as precise of a way to devalue the currency   as we did when we were pegged to gold, and I  think that we lend ourselves to competitive   devaluations from other developed countries. And the third thing is that devaluation may   help our current debt load as it stands today at  the government level, but the largest component of   our future liabilities are the entitlement  programs. I think today we have something   like $3 or $4 trillion of current entitlement  programs. That's obviously going to balloon over   the next 5 to 10 years. All of those entitlement  programs-- I believe there is a study that showed   maybe 19 or 20 of the programs have either  explicit or implicit inflation links within them.  

So they're all linked to inflation. So if  we have 5%, 6%, 7% inflation, it may reduce   our current debt load, but it's not going to  do a heck of a lot for our future debt load   because it's all basically linked to inflation. So one of the things that we're going to have   to grapple with are these entitlement issues. And  whether we remove the link to inflation-- to me,   that's some form of austerity because you're  giving people less than what they were promised. 

So I think that there's going to have to be some  form of austerity that comes down the road. And I   know people freak out when they hear the word  austerity because it's never possible, but   when we think about inflation as a  solution, inflation is not going to   solve the entitlement burden all that much. So I think that we continue to grind towards   weaker and weaker growth, and the social unrest  gets worse and worse until we either grapple with   the debt situation or we have a big problem  with the currency, which I think people can   be surprised by how long countries can hold  it together with really high levels of debt.   It mainly comes down to how much they  can keep the population under control.  But I think there's a scenario where the US could  be in a situation of 160%, 170%, 200% debt to GDP,   and the situation can still be, quote, unquote,  under control in terms of society continues to   operate with just with weaker and weaker growth.  So I think we continue to go down this path,   and I don't think there's a threshold to how  low real GDP per capita can go. I think that  

that upside-side U relationship continues until  we either have some form of forced austerity or   some sort of currency crisis, which  I wrote a recent note about that.  When you think about wealth preservation, there's  gold ETFs which are great for getting exposure,   but there's no substitute for physical gold. And  I wrote a note that having a percentage of your   net worth in physical gold is-- I would  think for me it's a prudent strategy to   guard against that type of scenario because  I think that the situation is lower growth,   lower inflation until it's not. And the until  it's not scenario is basically impossible to time,   also known as a Minsky moment. So I think  that that's how the end game plays out or the   end game as far as my eye can see it right now. LYN ALDEN: Yeah, there's been a similar argument  

for farmland because in some ways it has certain  characteristics similar to gold in that sense.   And I posted a chart a few weeks ago showing that   if you look at broad money supply per capita  and you look at the price per acre of farmland,   they've been highly correlated over  something like a 50-year period.  And I guess so if we were to kind of maybe  wrap this up by kind of separating different   types of inflation, I notice people from different  schools of thought debate about what is inflation?   whether or not it's accurately measured. And  they tend to be talking about different types   of inflation. And so, yeah, there are some  schools of thought that they basically view an   increase in the money supply as a form of  inflation. They generally would put some   caveats on that, different types-- how exactly  measure the money supply. But basically if the  

amount of currency units in a broad system  is increasing, then it's inflationary.  Then, of course, we have a basket of goods  that we can measure for inflation. And then,   of course, there's going to be debates about  whether that basket of goods is appropriate,   if the adjusters are appropriate,  and people will debate about that.  And a third type is potentially asset-price  inflation where, going back to the Tesla example,   say a company produces the same amount of cars  or 30% more cars but then its share prices are   5x or 10x higher. Basically you're  paying more money for the same  

kind of allocation of resources, essentially. And one thing I've found in my research is that   when you have that first type of inflation-- so  just say you have a massive increase in the broad   money supply. That ends up somewhere. And, of  course, the big question is where does it end up?   And the short answer is that it kind of ends up  in whatever it happens to be scarce and in demand.  And so if you have, say, overcapacity of  manufacturing or you have no problems,   no limitations there, it's not going to  show up in, say, commodities or products   because there's no scarcity, whereas it will  show up in things like prime real estate or   gold or growth stocks or things like that. So one of the things I'm looking out at the   long run is if we see money supply continue  to increase at a pretty substantial rate--   which you can get if you're running pretty  big deficits and then a lot of that's being   purchased in the secondary market by the Federal  Reserve. If you were to get that continued   currency inflation-- let's call it money-supply  inflation. Holding bonds in that environment  

seems somewhat challenging because even if you  don't get that inflation showing up in the CPI,   your purchasing power as it relates to, say, prime  real estate or gold or, say, really high-quality   equities could continue to diminish. So do you  have any sort of separation there? How would   you incorporate kind of that into your analysis? ERIC BASMAJIAN: Sure. So I think that's a great   point. I think that the inflation as it relates  to money supply can be tricky because if I,   let's say, print a trillion dollars of  currency and then I light it on fire,   that's not really inflationary. So as far as the basket of goods and services,  

why that's important is because that's what plays  into TIPS calculations and that's what plays into   the cost-of-living adjustments  with a lot of the entitlements. So   as much as people hate those metrics, we  have to use those metrics because that's what   is a huge factor in our future deficits  and as well as in the fixed-income market.  So I think we have to look at where  the money-supply growth is coming from.  

And if we look at it over the last year, let's  say, and we continue doing what we're doing,   a lot of it is coming from quantitative easing  and the secondary market, which is causing a huge   rise in deposits at the banks. And if you take  a nonbank that had a Treasury and then you take   the Treasury away from them and give them cash in  the form of a deposit, they're not going to invest   that going to the store and buying a sandwich.  They're going to recycle that back into financial   assets. So I think that the financial-asset  inflation can continue, and it can continue  

as long as this is the way that we're deciding  to increase the money supply. I don't think   that adversely affects Treasury investors who are targeting more of nominal GDP growth   because nominal GDP growth won't  increase really in that scenario.  The second thing I would note is that that game  can continue. And it's not that the market will  

rise in perpetuity as long as QE is going on  because one of the things we have to realize   is that, at the end of the day, these are equities  that need to be-- their debt needs to be serviced   with cash flow. So a company that may be in good  standing with their debt can see their equity   valuations rise quite dramatically, but if the  underlying economy gets so weak because all the   money supply is going back into financial assets,  then at some point some company somewhere is   literally not going to be able to make payment on  their bond. Commercial real estate, for example,   will literally not be able to make payment,  and then that asset is literally in default.   There's currently no mechanism for the Fed  to buy defaulting assets at the moment. 

So it could be akin to a scenario where you  increase money supply and light it on fire in   the sense that it could cause this really sharp  rise in the equity market. But if the underlying   economy gets so weak that a lot of these companies  don't have the cash flow to support their bonds,   they end up in bankruptcy. So we could see a large  rise in the money supply. It goes into the equity   market, and that paper wealth kind of vanishes.  That could also be a deflationary outcome.  So I think that holding bonds in this scenario  only gets quite dangerous if nominal GDP is rising   on a sustained basis. And for that, I would use  some of my shorter-term leading indicators to give   me a heads up as to when that's happening, which  it is now. So I'm not overweight long-term bonds  

at all, actually. I'm actually underweight  long-term bonds in this scenario because   the expectation that nominal  GDP growth is going to increase.  But the wild-mania speculation and QE field  asset-price inflation to me doesn't work   against the bond allocation all that much.  Specifically if you have a balanced portfolio   that does have a fair amount of equities within  it as well as gold as well as, aside from your   securities portfolio, a physical allocation to  gold, in that scenario I think that bonds still   do play a critical role in an overall portfolio. LYN ALDEN: Yeah, going back to that point about  

company cash flows and the ability to pay debts,  that's actually one of the concerns I have is that   we've seen such a speculative bubble, especially  the past several months where just if you look at,   say, what retail investors are doing with call  options and what we're seeing in the valuations   in some of these stocks, I think that when the  dust kind of settles on some of this, we see kind   of a rate-of-change reduction in the amount of,  say, money-supply increases or fiscal stimulus.   I think it's one of those things where the tide  goes out, and some of these things are kind of--   basically I think that their prices have been  bid up to a reasonable degree like, let's say,   gold. Whereas I think some of these other  things that actually have cash flows and then   they're

2021-03-15 15:58

Show Video

Other news